El trabajo de Philippe van Parijs NO EUROZONE WITHOUT EURO-DIVIDEND señala, más allá de su propuesta concreta, los problemas fundamentales del diseño de la eurozona y los derivados de las limitaciones políticas que se superponen a ellos.
Esta es su conclusión:
“Let us sum up. If the
analysis proposed here is correct, the euro-dividend
would equip the Eurozone
with an essential transfer-based stabilization mechanism analogous to the one
supplied to the dollar zone by the far more
complex and extensive
American welfare state. In addition, the euro-dividend would not make things
worse but, if anything, significantly better in terms of two other features
whose presence contributes to the sustainability of a currency area. Bearing
this in mind, we can now turn to a final question.
Suppose one is convinced
by the need for a euro-dividend, how is it to become politically feasible.
Firstly, perception is of
the greatest importance. There is little prospect for a euro-dividend if it is
successfully depicted as a mega-bureaucratic machine that threatens the valuable
democratically shaped diversity of national social protection systems and ends
up channelling masses of money from countries well run to countries sloppily
run, thereby perpetuating the latter’s sloppiness.
It is important that
European citizens should understand that a euro-dividend is not a threat to the
diversity of European welfare state, but instead, for the reasons explained
above, an essential tool to prevent the constraints of the single market and
the single currency from gradually forcing all of them to trim down and
converge to a minimalist form of social protection. Even
more important, the euro-dividend should at the same time be viewed as a way of
making as sure as possible that every European citizen should share in the material
benefits of European integration. How high these benefits are is impossible to
assess with any precision. To imagine the relevant counterfactual, one must
find some inspiration in the contrast between the aftermath of World War I and
that of World War II. The very fact that it is hard to think of a military
build up and armed conflict between European countries, let alone to estimate
what they would cost us, is not a reason to ignore them in the assessment of
the material benefits every European derives from the creation and perpetuation
of the European Union. They must on the contrary be taken into account as a
bulky and lasting component of what the EU keeps doing for us.
There are, in addition,
the considerable material benefits of a common market in terms of breaking
monopolies, stimulating innovation, facilitating specialization, etc.,
mostly reflected in the difference between the prices Europeans pay for the
goods and services they consume and the prices they would have paid had the
trade and investment barriers remained what they were prior to the European Economic Community. Arguably, this type of
benefit is directly shared by all, but it is so to various extents, as the
bundle of goods consumed by rich and poor is not the same. Moreover, greater
transnational competition also makes many jobs and many regions more
vulnerable. For the reasons discussed above, this vulnerability has been
further increased by monetary unification. Lower prices than would otherwise be
the case are therefore no guarantee of universal gain. In this context, the
euro-dividend would not prevent some people and regions from gaining a lot from
European integration nor some others from losing out. But it would give
everyone a tangible share in part of the overall material gain that can be
safely attributed to the very existence of the EU. Indexing the level of the
dividend on the EU wide per capita level of value added (or GDP) — or its
average over the last five years or so to make it less bumpy — would make this
link more explicit: the prosperity of the whole would then be clearly seen to
benefit each of its parts — member states, regions and households.
There are no doubt also
background institutional conditions that will favour this perception of the
euro-dividend and thereby its acceptability by the population, rather than a
perception in terms of immediate country-level net losses and net gains. As
long as key decisions are taken by politicians who are accountable exclusively
to the electorate of a single country, it will be very difficult to prevent
electoral competition from getting the issue framed in terms of net gainer and
net loosing countries. This is the case to the extent that the key decisions
are taken by heads of government gathered in the European Council. But it does
not need to be different if more power is exercised by the European Parliament,
meant to emanate from the EU population as a whole rather than from its member
states. As things stand, MEPs are also electorally accountable only to the
citizens of their own country. In the US and in European nations, an
inclusive rhetoric and policy orientation is facilitated by direct presidential
elections or centralized political parties. At EU level, there are good reasons
to believe that we shall never have either. The next best option is the development
of strong pan-EU federations of national parties, which itself will remain a
pipe dream in the absence of an EU-wide constituency for part of the seats of
the European Parliament, coupled with a direct link between the composition of
the EU executive and the electoral results in this constituency.
More broadly still, the
political achievability and sustainability of a euro dividend— and of any other
major redistributive scheme at EU level — requires the existence and liveliness
of an EU-wide democratic forum. An EU-wide parliamentary constituency should
help, but will not suffice. Institutional innovations such as the European
Citizens’ Initiatives should also help, because of the opportunities and
incentives they create to meet, argue and mobilize across national borders. The
most fundamental obstacle, however, is the EU’s linguistic diversity. National
welfare states were not born out of the blue through some top-down decree. They
were the laborious outcomes of long struggles. Such struggles could only be
successful because of efficient communication, trust building, coordination and
mobilization across the nation made possible by a shared national language. The
wonderful yet expensive and stiffening services of translators and interpreters
will never supply an adequate alternative to a shared language. As mentioned
before, competence in English is spreading rapidly among the younger cohorts of
the European population. But this lingua franca should not and will not replace
national languages. It will not therefore be able to play
quite the same role as national languages in cementing trust and
fostering solidarity. Nonetheless a minimal condition for the political
sustainability of institutionalized solidarity is that the people among whom
this solidarity operates should be able to address and understand each other.
The democratization and appropriation of English as a lingua franca throughout Europe is therefore at least as crucial to the political
feasibility of EU-wide redistribution as institutional engineering.
What follows from this
brief discussion of political feasibility is not that we might as well give up. It
is rather that it is not enough to spell out blueprints of what is needed to
get to the roots of our present problems, submit them to critical scrutiny and
advocate what emerges as the most robust version. At the same time, one must
fight and progress on many different, seemingly unconnected fronts. Banning the
dubbing of films may be no less crucial to the sustainability of an EU-wide
transfer system than removing the cap on the EU’s taxing powers.”
(Philippe van Parijs: No
Eurozone without euro-dividend)
No comments:
Post a Comment