DERECHO TRIBUTARIO Y CONSTITUCIONAL DERECHO Y NUEVAS TECNOLOGIAS ACTUALIDAD JURIDICA Y ECONOMICA MEDIOAMBIENTE
Licencia Creative Commons
Esta obra está bajo una Licencia Creative Commons Atribución-NoComercial-SinDerivadas 4.0 Internacional.
Friday, March 29, 2019
Wednesday, March 27, 2019
EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT: HOUSE AND TRAGEDY OF THE ANTICOMMONS (II)
THE TRAGEDY OF THE ANTICOMMONS
By
Michael Heller
The anticommons is a paradox.
While private ownership usually increases wealth, too much ownership has the
opposite effect: it wrecks markets, stops innovation, and costs lives. We can
reclaim the wealth lost in a tragedy of the anticommons. But it takes tools to
end ownership gridlock. The following pages provide the basic analytic tools
you need: a brief overview of the anticommons lexicon (Heller 2008; 2010).
THE TRILOGY OF OWNERSHIP
Traditionally, ownership has
been categorized into three basic types: private, commons, and state property
(Heller 2001). Let’s unpack those categories:
(…)
Commons property refers to
shared resources, resources for which there is no single decision maker. In
turn, the commons can be divided into two distinct categories (Eggertsson
2002). The first is open access, a regime in which no one at all can be
excluded, like on the high seas. Mistakenly, the legal and economics
literatures long conflated the commons with open access, hence reinforcing the
link between commons and tragedy. The second type of commons has many names,
but for now let’s call it group access, a regime in which a limited number of
commoners can exclude outsiders but not each other. If the ocean is open
access, then a small pond surrounded by a handful of landowners may be group
access. Group access is often overlooked even though it is the predominant form
of commons ownership, and is often not tragic at all; it is the core concept
that this volume celebrates.
Privatizing a commons may cure
the tragedy of wasteful overuse, but it may inadvertently spark the opposite.
English lacks a term to denote wasteful underuse. To describe this type of
fragmentation, I coined the phrase tragedy of the anticommons (Heller 1998).
The term covers any setting in which too many people can block each other from
creating or using a valuable resource. Rightly understood, the opposite of
overuse in a commons is underuse in an anticommons.
This concept makes visible the
hidden half of our ownership spectrum, a world of social relations as complex
and extensive as any we have previously known (Figure 2). Beyond normal private
property lies anticommons ownership. As one commentator has noted, “To simplify
a little, the tragedy of the commons tells us why things are likely to fall
apart, and the tragedy of the anticommons helps explain why it is often so hard
to get them back together” (Fennell 2004).
(…)
THE SPREAD OF THE ANTICOMMONS IDEA
After I proposed the
possibility of anticommons tragedy, Nobel laureate James Buchanan and his
colleague Yong Yoon undertook to create a formal economic model. They wrote
that the anticommons concept helps explain “how and why potential economic
value may disappear into the ‘black hole’ of resource underutilization”
(Buchanan and Yoon 2000).” In recent years, economic modeling of the
anticommons has become quite sophisticated.
To date, the most debated
application of anticommons theory has been in the area of drug patents and
innovation (Heller and Eisenberg 1998). Since my 1998 Science article
with Rebecca Eisenberg, there has been a flurry of follow-on papers and
reports, many concluding that patents should be harder to obtain, in part to
avoid potential anticommons tragedy effects. A recent book on the patent crisis
concludes that, “the structure of the biotechnology industry seems likely to
run high anticommons risks,” particularly when companies are attempting to
bring products to market (Burk and Lemley 2009).
It’s not just biomedical
research that’s susceptible to anticommons tragedy. The framework has been
applied across the high tech frontier, ranging from broadcast spectrum
ownership to technology patents. Also, cutting edge art and music are about mashing
up and remixing many separately owned bits of culture. Even with land, the most
socially important projects require assembling multiple parcels. Innovation has
moved on, but we’re stuck with old-style ownership that’s easy to fragment and
hard to put together.
Anticommons theory is now well
established, but empirical studies have yet to catch up. How hard is it to
negotiate around ownership fragmentation? How much does ownership fragmentation
slow down technological innovation? Does the effect vary by industry? It is
difficult to measure discoveries that should have been made but weren’t,
solutions that could exist but don’t. We are just starting to examine these
conundrums. A recent study reported experimental findings that reject the
presumed symmetry of commons and anticommons and find instead that anticommons
dilemmas “seem to elicit more individualistic behavior than commons dilemmas”
and are “more prone to underuse than commons dilemmas are to overuse.” The
researchers conclude that “if commons leads to ‘tragedy,’ anticommons may well
lead to ‘disaster’” (Vanneste et al 2006).
TOWARD A NEW LEXICON
We have millennia of practice
in spotting tragedies of overuse. When too many people fish, fisheries are
depleted. When too many people pollute, we choke on dirty air. Then, we spring
into action with market-based, cooperative, and legislative solutions. But
underuse caused by multiple owners is unfamiliar. The affected resource is hard
to spot. Our language is new. Even though a tragedy of the anticommons may be
as costly to society as the more familiar forms of resource misuse, we have
never noticed, debated, or learned how to fix underuse. As a first step, we
need to name the phenomenon: the tragedy of the anticommons should join our
lexicon.
Michael Heller (USA) is the Lawrence A. Wien Professor of Real Estate Law at Columbia Law School. He is the author of The Gridlock Society (2008) and Commons and Anticommons(2010).
La Directiva de Copyright aprobada por el Parlamento Europeo facilitaría los efectos descritos como tragedia de los anticomunes y lo hace, además, en un ámbito directamente afectado por la libertad de expresión en el mundo actual: reduciendo su cantidad
EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT: HOUSE AND TRAGEDY OF THE ANTICOMMONS (I)
How the political groups voted on #uploadfilters and the #linktax:— Julia Reda (@Senficon) 26 de marzo de 2019
• @eppgroup overwhelmingly in favour
• @theprogressives & @aldegroup significantly in favour
• @GreensEP & @GUENGL overwhelmingly opposed#SaveYourInternet pic.twitter.com/x12Rp4q1Lm
Tuesday, March 26, 2019
MACAULAY (HOUSE OF COMMONS, 1841)-PARLAMENTO EUROPEO
Macaulay se dirigía a los Comunes, en Febrero de 1841,
con ocasión de una extensión rechazada en la duración de los derechos de
propiedad intelectual en estos términos, que no han perdido actualidad, a la
vista de la decisión del Parlamento Europeo de hoy:
"Copyright is
monopoly, and produces all the effects which the general voice of mankind
attributes to monopoly. My honourable and learned friend talks very
contemptuously of those who are led away by the theory that monopoly makes
things dear. That monopoly makes things dear is certainly a theory, as
all the great truths which have been established by the experience of all ages
and nations, and which are taken for granted in all reasonings, may be said to
be theories. It is a theory in the same sense in which it is a theory that day
and night follow each other, that lead is heavier than water, that bread
nourishes, that arsenic poisons, that alcohol intoxicates. If, as my honourable
and learned friend seems to think, the whole world is in the wrong on this
point, if the real effect of monopoly is to make articles good and cheap, why
does he stop short in his career of change? Why does he limit the operation of
so salutary a principle to sixty years? Why does he consent to anything short
of a perpetuity? He told us that in consenting to anything short of a
perpetuity he was making a compromise between extreme right and expediency. But
if his opinion about monopoly be correct, extreme right and expediency would
coincide. Or rather, why should we not restore the monopoly of the East India
trade to the East India Company? (...)
The question of
copyright, Sir, like most questions of civil prudence, is neither black nor
white, but grey.The system of copyright has great advantages and great
disadvantages; and it is our business to ascertain what these are, and then to
make an arrangement under which the advantages may be as far as possible
secured, and the disadvantages as far as possible excluded. The charge which I
bring against my honourable and learned friend's bill is this, that it leaves
the advantages nearly what they are at present, and increases the disadvantages
at least fourfold.
(...)
Now, I will not
affirm that the existing law is perfect, that it exactly hits the point at
which the monopoly ought to cease; but this I confidently say, that the
existing law is very much nearer that point than the law proposed by my
honourable and learned friend. For consider this; the evil effects of the
monopoly are proportioned to the length of its duration. But the good effects
for the sake of which we bear with the evil effects are by no means
proportioned to the length of its duration. A monopoly of sixty years produces
twice as much evil as a monopoly of thirty years, and thrice as much evil as a
monopoly of twenty years. But it is by no means the fact that a posthumous
monopoly of sixty years gives to an author thrice as much pleasure and thrice
as strong a motive as a posthumous monopoly of twenty years. On the contrary,
the difference is so small as to be hardly perceptible.”
Preguntas para nuestros ilustres europarlamentarios y
para el defensor del proyecto Herr Voss:
¿Quién cobra y explota por el derecho sobre el
protocolo de internet que hace posible su existencia y difusión y la de todos
los contenidos disponibles en la misma?
¿Cuántos "layers" adicionales de derechos
sin cobro y explotación hacen posible su existencia y difusión y la de todos
los contenidos disponibles en la red?
¿Cómo es posible que el protocolo de internet y todas
las innovaciones necesarias para su ejecución se hayan desarrollado sin los
incentivos y modificaciones que la actual reforma dice introducir en beneficio
de los autores?
¿Qué es lo que dicen los estudios empíricos del pasado
con copyright sobre la retribución de los autores?
¿En qué modo debe estar garantizada la libertad
constitucional -y garantizada por la Carta de los Derechos Fundamentales de la
Unión Europea- de expresión en internet y hasta qué punto puede limitarse en la
forma establecida?
¿Se ha tenido en cuenta el artículo 100 de la
Directiva 2018/1972 (Salvaguardias de derechos fundamentales)?:
“1. Las medidas nacionales relativas al
acceso o al uso por parte de los usuarios finales de los servicios y las
aplicaciones a través de redes de comunicaciones electrónicas respetarán la
Carta de los Derechos Fundamentales de la Unión Europea (en lo sucesivo,
«Carta») y los principios generales del Derecho de la Unión.
2.Cualquier medida relativa al acceso o al
uso por parte de los usuarios finales de los servicios y las aplicaciones a
través de redes de comunicaciones electrónicas, que sea susceptible de limitar
el ejercicio de los derechos y libertades reconocidos en la Carta solo
podrá imponerse si está prevista por ley y respeta tales derechos o libertades,
es proporcionada, necesaria, y responde efectivamente a objetivos de interés
general reconocidos por el Derecho de la Unión o a la necesidad de protección
de los derechos y libertades de los demás en línea con el artículo 52, apartado
1, de la Carta y con los principios generales del Derecho de la Unión, que
incluyen el derecho a la tutela judicial efectiva y a un juicio justo. Por lo
tanto, dichas medidas solo podrán ser adoptadas respetando debidamente el
principio de presunción de inocencia y el derecho a la intimidad. Se
garantizará un procedimiento previo, justo e imparcial, que incluirá el derecho
de los interesados a ser oídos, sin perjuicio de que concurran las condiciones
y los arreglos procesales adecuados en los casos de urgencia debidamente
justificados, de conformidad con la Carta.”
No Sr. De Grandes, no es cierto lo que afirma:
"Los derechos de
autor son un derecho de propiedad como cualquier otro derecho de propiedad, sea
este material o no. Y existe para que los artistas puedan vivir de sus obras,
por eso nuestro deber es protegerlo, sin los derechos de autor muchas obras,
sean musicales, cinematográficas o de otro tipo, no existirían", afirmó De
Grandes
Macaulay lo dijo ya hace 188 años. Lo
recordamos de nuevo debidamente traducido:
El copyright es un monopolio y produce
todos los efectos que el consenso general de la humanidad atribuye a los monopolios
(…) El sistema de copyright tiene grandes ventajas y grandes desventajas, y es
nuestro cometido determinar unas y otras y adoptar una decisión que asegure,
todo lo posible, las ventajas y excluya, todo lo posible, las desventajas. La
acusación que traigo contra el proyecto legislativo de mi honorable e instruido
amigo es que deja las ventajas tal y como son en la actualidad e incrementa las
desventajas al menos cuatro veces.
(Macaulay, alocución en The House of Commons, 1841)
Eso –debidamente actualizado teniendo en cuenta el
nacimiento y desarrollo de internet- es lo que en esencia han dicho la inmensa
mayoría de los expertos y no expertos en Europa y fuera de Europa en contra de
la reforma aprobada hoy por los europarlamentarios.
Lo mismo indicó Mancur Olson ya en 1982:
Las coaliciones de distribución retardan
la capacidad de una sociedad para adoptar nuevas tecnologías y para reasignar
recursos en respuesta a las condiciones cambiantes, reduciendo así la tasa de
crecimiento económico.
NOTA PARA ESPAÑA:
Los
eurodiputados de PP, PSOE, Ciudadanos, PDeCAT y PNV votaron a favor del texto
este martes en Estrasburgo. En contra se pronunciaron Podemos, ERC, ICV y EQUO.
(26-03-2019) APROBADA LA DIRECTIVA MÁS CONTESTADA DE LA HISTORIA DE LA UE
The European Parliament has adopted the copyright directive 348-274. The EU will get #uploadfilters and a counterproductive right for press publishers. #Article13 #Article11 #SaveYourInternet pic.twitter.com/Cu9eyI2Xqo— Creative Commons (@creativecommons) 26 de marzo de 2019
LA UNIÓN EUROPEA ELIMINARÁ EL DERECHO A MEZCLAR
Lawrence Lessig: The EU will kill the right to remix in #Rome #Italy lessig-kill-remix-john-cabot-university/296559769 pic.twitter.com/TdaRHoi1BX— Aaron Swartz Day (@aaronswartzIT) 21 de marzo de 2019
Monday, March 25, 2019
Sunday, March 24, 2019
Thursday, March 21, 2019
Tuesday, March 19, 2019
Saturday, March 16, 2019
Friday, March 15, 2019
EL CRECIMIENTO, LA CAPITALIZACIÓN Y LA DEUDA
The post-2009 rally is the most expensive of all time. Debt has risen by almost $60tn since GFC, meaning that econ rebound of past decade, which brought global GDP increase of $20tn and a rise in mkt cap of $52tn, has been bought at high price. https://t.co/Vid1z4kBfD via @welt pic.twitter.com/XCPPi89zdd— Holger Zschaepitz (@Schuldensuehner) 14 de marzo de 2019
Thursday, March 14, 2019
Wednesday, March 13, 2019
Monday, March 11, 2019
Sunday, March 10, 2019
Thursday, March 7, 2019
Monday, March 4, 2019
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)